Loading [MathJax]/jax/output/HTML-CSS/jax.js

2.2 Short Run and Long Run - Class Notes

Contents

Overview

Today we continue with setting up the second stage of the firm’s problem, the cost-minimization problem, where firms choose inputs (l,k) that minimize total cost (wl+rk) in order to produce the optimal amount of output q. For now, we are merely assuming the amount of output that is optimal, later we will explicitly solve for it as our first stage (profit maximization problem).

In doing so, we need to split up production activity into the short-run, where firms cannot change all inputs (we traditionally assume capital is fixed ˉk and firms can only change labor l), and the long run, where firms can change all inputs. We discuss short run production and associated input-based metrics: marginal product and average product.

In the long-run, firms can choose many combinations of inputs (l,k) that yield a desired output. We introduce two tools that will remind you a lot like the tools from consumer theory: (1) an isoquant curveCall it an output curve to remember it better.

that, similar to an indifference curve, contains all the combinations of inputs that yield the same output, and (2) an isocost lineCall it just a cost line to remember it better.

that, similar to a budget constraint, contains all the combinations of inputs that are the same total cost. We discuss some properties about each of these things and do some examples in anticipation of puttiung these tools together in the next class to solve the problem.

For some students, it takes this second time around with the tools of consumer theory for them to finally “click,” and that’s okay!

Note to section 1 (Tu/Th) students: this formerly included the material that has now been separated into class 12 (on solving the cost minimization problem), but I’ve since broke it into its own class to better keep track of our schedule.

Slides

Appendix

Solving the Firm’s Problem in One Step

Traditionally, it is easier if we break the firm’s profit maximization problem into two stages:

  1. The firm’s profit maximization problem:
  1. The firm’s cost minimization problem:

We proceed in class with the second stage first, and then the first stage. However, this appendix shows that the problem can be solved in a single stage. For simplicity, we look at the short run, where there is a single input l that can be chosen (ˉk is fixed).

The firm’s profit maximization problem:

Objective: Maximize Profits

The objective function is trying to maximize profits. So we need to think about different levels (“contour lines”) of profit that correspond to combinations of input and output (at constant prices).This is similar to finding indifference curves for consumers’ attempting to maximize their utility function (by finding the highest indifference curve for their budget).

A firm earns profits (π) as revenues minus costs: π=pywl Where - q: quantity of output - p: price of output - w: price of input (wage) - l: quantity of input (labor)

Imagine different amounts of input and output that would generate the same profit. We can think of an isoprofit line as having the equation above.

However, it’s easier if we graph it as output in terms of input (our two axes for drawing the production function): π=pqwlπ+wl=pyπp+wpl=q

For these example isoprofit lines, since the price of our input (w) is $1, and the price of output (p) is $2, the slope of each of the isoprofit lines is positive 0.5.

Constraint: Technology

The constraint is what is technologically feasible for the firm to produce, according to its production function. We need to make a few assumptions about production functions in order to get an optimum solution:

  1. q>0: firms always produce a positive amount
  2. dqdl>0: The more inputs used, the more output produced (the marginal product, i.e. the slope of production function, i.e. it’s first derivative, is positive)
  3. d2qdl2<0: Diminishing marginal productivity (production increases at a decreasing rate, i.e. the second derivative of the production function is negative)

These assumptions generate decreasing returns to scale in production: doubling input produces less than double output. These assumptions give us a mathematically-easy answer to find, but not all production fits these assumptions. A production function that fits these assumptions would look like this:

Solving the Problem

Essentially, we are trying to find the highest profit line tangent to our production function:

At a tangency, the slopes of the two functions are equal. The slope of the isoprofit lines we know are wp. The slope of the production function is the marginal product (of labor). So at the point of tangency: Slope of production function=Slope of Isoprofit lineMPl=wp

The Firm’s Supply and Demand Functions

The Geometry of Short-Run Production

This appendix explores the geometry of production functions in the short run. From the common law of diminishing returns (sometimes called “the law of variable proportions”), with constant technology, increasing the use of one factor (e.g. l), holding other factors constant (e.g. ˉk), will ultimately experience diminishing returns. We often break up short-run production into three stages, based on the type of returns to increasing the use of one factor: increasing, decreasing, and negative.

I. Increasing Returns

In Stage I, labor experiences increasing returns. Both the marginal and the average product of labor are positive and (mostly) increasing. That is to say, output is increasing at an increasing rate when more labor is added, and the productivity per worker increases. For the example above, Stage I occurs over the range of 0-6 workers.

Intuitively, increasing returns means that output increases at an increasing rate. This is not the same, but you can think of this almost like exponential growth – just by adding a few more units of input we can get massive amounts of output. If this held forever, we could grow the entire world’s supply of food in a single flower pot!

Note that at 4 workers, marginal product reaches a maximum. Beyond this point, marginal product remains positive but begins to decrease. Looking at the production function, at 4 workers, the production function is at an inflection point. After 4 workers, the production function continues to increase, but now at a decreasing rate.

Geometrically, what this means is that between 0-4 workers, the production function is convex (a line connecting two points is above the function), between 4-6 workers, the production function is concave (a line connecting two points is below the function), the inflection point at 4 is where it switches between convex and concave.

Stage I ends not at 4 laborers, where marginal product is maximized, but at 6 workers, where the marginal product and average product intersect (are equal).

In practice, most firms breeze through Stage I very quickly. Naturally, if firms can boost output a lot, and cheaply, just by adding a worker or two, they will keep hiring workers and hiring workers…

II. Decreasing Returns

In Stage II, labor experiences diminishing returns. As we discussed with the law of diminishing returns, this will eventually happen to all factors of production if you keep adding them (holding other factors constant). Now, output is increasing, but at a decreasing rate. Adding more workers will increase output, but by progressively less and less, and each worker also is less productive on average, since both average and marginal product is declining (though total product is increasing). For the example above, Stage II occurs over the range of 6-8 workers.

Stage II ends at 8 workers, where the marginal product falls to zero.

In practice, most firms operate in Stage II, so this range is sometimes called the economic region’’ of short run production. We have seen that it is in the interest of a firm to keep adding labor during Stage I. We will next see that it is disadvantageous for a firm to keep adding labor beyond Stage II. Hence, the optimal amount of labor is often somewhere in Stage II.

III. Negative Returns

In Stage III, labor experiences negative returns, that is, adding labor actually decreases output! Here we have the “too many cooks in the kitchen” phenomenon. For the example above, Stage III happens when the firm is using 8 or more workers. We can see that the marginal product is negative, and average product continues to decline, as does output.

Recall diminishing returns implies that we are adding labor but holding all other factors (e.g. capital) constant. It is possible to increase the number of workers beyond 8 and still increase output, but that would require an increase in capital. If we do not increase capital, then by continually adding labor we will eventually hit diminishing (and negative) returns.

Stage Output MPl APl
I at rate, then at rate , then
II at rate
III Negative

The Relationship Between Marginal and Average

There is a consistent relationship between any marginal magnitude and any average magnitude. We will see this when we talk about production, about costs, revenues, profits, etc.

When the marginal is greater than the average, the average is increasing because the marginal “pulls up” the average. When the marginal is less than the average, the average is decreasing because the marginal “pulls down” the average. Therefore, average is neither increasing nor decreasing (reaches a maximum/minimum) when the marginal equals the average.

Think of your grades or your GPA. Suppose your average is a B, and you get back a (marginal) grade that is an A. Since the marginal is higher than the average, this pulls up your average. Suppose instead you get back a (marginal) grade that is a C. Since the marginal is lower than the average, this pulls down your average.

Case APl
MPl>APl
MPl=APl Maximized
MPl<APl

Look at the lower panel of the figure above and you can see, in Stage I, MPl>APl and thus APl is increasing. The transition to Stage II occurs where MPl=APl and thus APl reaches its maximum. In Stage III, MPl<APl and thus APl is falling.

If these graphs looks vaguely familiar, cost curves (total cost, marginal cost, average cost) are monetized reciprocals of product curves (total product, marginal product, average product). Here is a proof (that will make sense a few lessons from now):

MC(q)=VC(q)q=wlq=w1MPl

AVC(q)=VCq=wlq=w1APl