There's a lot more to game theory than a one-shot prisoners' dilemma:
one shot vs. repeated game
discrete vs. continuous strategies
perfect vs. incomplete vs. and asymmetric information
simultaneous vs. sequential game
See my game theory course for more (likely taught next in Fall 2021)
We use "solution concepts" to allow us to predict an equilibrium of a game
Nash Equilibrium is the primarly solution concept
Important about Nash equilibrium:
N.E. ≠ the "best" or optimal outcome
Game may have multiple N.E.
Game may have no N.E. (in "pure" strategies)
1) Cell-by-Cell Inspection: look in each cell, does either player want to deviate?
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 1's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 2's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
N.E.: each player is playing a best response
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Two Nash equilibria again: (A,A) and (B,B)
But here (A,A) ≻ (B,B)!
Path Dependence: early choices may affect later ability to choose or switch
Lock-in: the switching cost of moving from one equilibrium to another becomes prohibitive
Suppose we are currently in equilibrium (B,B)
Inefficient lock-in:
We consider an Entry Game, a sequential game played between a potential Entrant and an Incumbent
A sequence of play: Entrant moves first, Incumbent moves second
Note: the magnitude of the payoffs don't really matter, only their relative sizes
This game is depicted in "Extensive form" or a game tree
Each player faces at least one "decision node" (solid, colored by player)
We need to talk more about strategies
Pure strategy: a player's complete plan of action for every possible contingency
if we reach node 1, I will play X; if we reach node 2, I will play Y; if ...
Entrant has 2 pure strategies:
Incumbent has 2 pure strategies:
Note Incumbent's strategy only comes into play if Entrant plays Enter and the game reaches node I.1
Backward induction: to determine the outcome of the game, start with the last-mover (i.e. decision nodes just before terminal nodes)
What is that mover's best choice to maximize their payoff?
Incumbent will Accommodate if game reaches I.1
Given this, what will Entrant do at E.1?
Entrant will Enter at E.1
Continue until we've reached the initial node (beginning)
We have the outcome:
(Enter, Accommodate)
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Perfect competition: no firm wants to raise or lower price given the market price ✓
Monopolist maximizes π by setting q∗: MR=MC and p∗=Demand(q∗)
This is an equilibrium, but is it the only equilibrium?
We've assumed just a single player in the model
What about potential competition?
Incumbent which sets its price pI
Entrant decides to stay out or enter the market, setting its price pE
Suppose firms have costs of C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c, then Entrant would enter and set pE=pI−ϵ (for arbitrary ϵ>0)
Suppose firms have costs of C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c, then Entrant would enter and set pE=pI−ϵ (for arbitrary ϵ>0)
Nash Equilibrium: incumbent sets pI=c, no entry
A market with a single firm, but the competitive outcome!
What if the entrant has higher costs than the incumbent: cE>cI?
Nash equilibrium: incumbent sets pI=pE−ϵ
Entrant stays out
One firm, but not a worst case monopoly
What if the entrant has higher costs than the incumbent: cE>cI?
Nash equilibrium: incumbent sets pI=pE−ϵ
Entrant stays out
One firm, but not a worst case monopoly
C(q)=cq+fMC(q)=cAC(q)=c+fq
πp=MC=−fq<0
Nash equilibrium: Incumbent prices at pI=AC earns π=0
Entrant stays out
Again, single firm, but not a monopoly
Fixed costs ⟹ do not vary with output
If firm exits, could sell these assets (e.g. machines, real estate) to recover costs
But what if assets are not sellable and costs not recoverable - i.e. sunk costs?
e.g. research and development, spending to build brand equity, advertising, worker-training for industry-specific skills, etc
These are bygones to the Incumbent, who has already committed to producing
But are new costs and risk to Entrant, lowering expected profits
In effect, sunk costs raise cE>cI, and return us back to our second example
Nash equilibrium: Incumbent deters entry with pI=pE−ϵ
Markets are contestable if:
Economies of scale need not be inconsistent with competitive markets (as is assumed) if they are contestable
Generalizes "prefect competition" model in more realistic way, also game-theoretic
William Baumol
(1922--2017)
"This means that...an incumbent, even if he can threaten retaliation after entry, dare not offer profit-making opportunities to potential entrants because an entering firm can hit and run, gathering in the available profits and departing when the going gets rough."
Baumol, William, J, 1982, "Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure," American Economic Review, 72(1): 1-15
Regulation & antitrust (once) focus(ed) on number of firms
Perfect competition as "gold standard", only market arrangement that is socially efficient:
But number of firms is endogenous and can evolve over time!
A more dynamic situation: firms respond over time
Perfect competition not the only socially efficient market-structure
Regulation and antitrust should consider whether a market is contestable, not just the number of firms
Firms engaging in egregious monopolistic behavior (↓q, ↑p, p>MC, π>0) largely persist because of barriers to entry
Business activities or political dealings with the goal to raise cE>cI
"Of far greater concern to Microsoft is the competition from new and emerging technologies, some of which are currently visible and others of which certainly are not. This array of known, emerging, and wholly unknown competitors places enormous pressure on Microsoft to price competitively and innovate aggressively." (Schmalensee 1999)
In perfect competition (model):
This is a tendency only because of free entry and exit
Don't judge real markets by their similarity to the perfect competition model
Judge them more on their level of contestability, ease of potential entry
"...In that Empire, the Art of Cartography attained such Perfection that the map of a single Province occupied the entirety of a City, and the map of the Empire, the entirety of a Province. In time, those Unconscionable Maps no longer satisfied, and the Cartographers Guilds struck a Map of the Empire whose size was that of the Empire, and which coincided point for point with it. The following Generations, who were not so fond of the Study of Cartography as their Forebears had been, saw that that vast Map was Useless..."
Jorge Luis Borges, 1658, On Exactitude in Science
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |